From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Good-deal bounds)

Good–deal bounds are price bounds for a financial portfolio which depends on an individual trader's preferences. Mathematically, if is a set of portfolios with future outcomes which are "acceptable" to the trader, then define the function by

where is the set of final values for self-financing trading strategies. Then any price in the range does not provide a good deal for this trader, and this range is called the "no good-deal price bounds." [1] [2]

If then the good-deal price bounds are the no-arbitrage price bounds, and correspond to the subhedging and superhedging prices. The no-arbitrage bounds are the greatest extremes that good-deal bounds can take. [2] [3]

If where is a utility function, then the good-deal price bounds correspond to the indifference price bounds. [2]

References

  1. ^ Jaschke, Stefan; Kuchler, Uwe (2000). "Coherent Risk Measures, Valuation Bounds, and ()-Portfolio Optimization". {{ cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= ( help)
  2. ^ a b c John R. Birge (2008). Financial Engineering. Elsevier. pp. 521–524. ISBN  978-0-444-51781-4.
  3. ^ Arai, Takuji; Fukasawa, Masaaki (2011). "Convex risk measures for good deal bounds". arXiv: 1108.1273v1 [ q-fin.PR].


From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Good-deal bounds)

Good–deal bounds are price bounds for a financial portfolio which depends on an individual trader's preferences. Mathematically, if is a set of portfolios with future outcomes which are "acceptable" to the trader, then define the function by

where is the set of final values for self-financing trading strategies. Then any price in the range does not provide a good deal for this trader, and this range is called the "no good-deal price bounds." [1] [2]

If then the good-deal price bounds are the no-arbitrage price bounds, and correspond to the subhedging and superhedging prices. The no-arbitrage bounds are the greatest extremes that good-deal bounds can take. [2] [3]

If where is a utility function, then the good-deal price bounds correspond to the indifference price bounds. [2]

References

  1. ^ Jaschke, Stefan; Kuchler, Uwe (2000). "Coherent Risk Measures, Valuation Bounds, and ()-Portfolio Optimization". {{ cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= ( help)
  2. ^ a b c John R. Birge (2008). Financial Engineering. Elsevier. pp. 521–524. ISBN  978-0-444-51781-4.
  3. ^ Arai, Takuji; Fukasawa, Masaaki (2011). "Convex risk measures for good deal bounds". arXiv: 1108.1273v1 [ q-fin.PR].



Videos

Youtube | Vimeo | Bing

Websites

Google | Yahoo | Bing

Encyclopedia

Google | Yahoo | Bing

Facebook